7
In this chapter we examine the relationship between animal welfare and protection policy and organisations that use animals – directly or indirectly – largely for commercial purposes. Unlike the animal protection organisations (APOs) discussed in Chapter 6, these organisations fit clearly into the interest-group model introduced at the start of that chapter. They are predominantly formally constituted organisations, largely designed to represent the interests of business and professionals externally, with the primary objective of producing an environment favourable to the production of ‘private goods’. Because of this, animal-using industry organisations (AIOs) may be seen as more homogeneous than APOs. However, this is not necessarily the case. While their profit-making objective is straightforward, this group of organisations is complex compared with other sectors of the economy. Partially, this is an artefact of the convergence of two policy concerns – animal welfare and economic protection – but it also relates to the extremely long history of some AIOs and variations in the industries that they represent.
This chapter begins by discussing the structure of AIOs as a collective group, before examining how animal welfare policy is made. It argues that policy-making is predominantly undertaken within the comparatively closed and close policy networks of animal-using industries in a regularised set of relationships with government organisations. Importantly, while animal welfare has increased in significance for AIOs over the last 40 years, the issue remains a comparatively minor – if increasing – problem from the perspective of AIO executives. They face a ‘grassfire war’ in which slow, consistent policy processes tend to be disrupted by APOs in a recurrent but unpredictable manner. Because of this, the later part of the chapter discusses how AIOs have, individually and collectively, responded to the challenge of APOs, and the pressures that this demonstrates within this community.
In looking at animal welfare, in Chapter 3 we identified the wide range of contexts in which humans have instrumental and commercial relations with animals. Thus, in describing AIOs, our net is wide, incorporating industries and quasi-industries1 that use animals as commodities; transform animals into other products such as food and clothing; transport and retail animals and animal products; and employ animals as labour and as research and teaching tools. As noted, there are about 500 organisations theoretically involved in the animal protection and welfare domain in Australia. Of this, about half are the APOs and related organisations discussed in Chapter 6. The remaining 250 or so are organisations involved in the use of animals for instrumental purposes.
This necessitates the observation that, as with Australian APOs, the large number is potentially misleading. It may give rise to the image of an army of lobbyists and organisations active in the policy space at any one time, but this is not the case: as with APOs, while some organisations are purely advocacy groups, many others have little or no role in direct political advocacy (Halpin 2005a). Instead, they may be focused on the provision of services within their membership group or sector, or engaged in some other type of activity, such as marketing. Some are ‘potential’ actors – that is, groups that are rarely called upon for policy expertise, but that may take action when called upon or in response to a threat or challenge; Schudson 1998, 310–1). Others play a policy role that is outside the remit of the state, such as in the regulation of pure-breed standards, or are only marginally ‘industrial’.
With this in mind, it is possible to divide Australian AIOs into eight general types:
This organisational breakdown, while lacking the sharpness of true typology, provides a good overview of the diversity of relevant actors who are, have been, or could be engaged with the domain. As with APOs, these organisations are diverse and, as with the Animal Welfare Leagues (AWLs) and RSPCAs, some have enabling legislation that governs some of their functions and provides a direct interface with the public sector. Where they differ is in their considerable financial and human resources, their presence throughout Australia, and their long-standing relationships with policy-makers. This means that the state (whether regularly or occasionally) has an interest in engaging with these groups to advance its policy objectives. A map of the AIOs and their relationship with state policy-makers is provided in Appendix D.
The diverse range of organisations across the domain mitigates against a coherent and consistent set of organisational responses to issues. Significant institutional actors in the policy network are commodity councils and industry sector organisations dealing with specific issues seen as unique to their sector. The main interlocutors of these organisations are state governments and major APOs. There is limited horizontal interaction across industry. What horizontal interaction exists tends to focus on those organisations most similar in structural, cultural and historical terms. This results in a de facto fire-breaking, for example, of agricultural organisations from those engaged in companion-animal policy debates.
The significance of state agencies as primary sites of policy development and consultation is an important part of this story, reducing the role of national peak representative bodies like the NFF as potential co-ordinating bridges, but also defining the policy paradigm in which organisational participation is interpreted and anticipated. Further, while this is exacerbated by the abolition of bridging structures like the Australian Animal Welfare Strategy (AAWS) (Chapter 8), even these structures tended to include selective industry representation within their specific code development processes, ‘siloing’ policy-making to a large extent. Because of this, commodity councils tended to see the AAWS process as comparatively clear, while cross-sectoral industry representatives reported the process as opaque.
Within some communities of AIOs, there has been discussion of less disaggregated ways to engage in industry advocacy. In 2015, the NFF and some SFOs engaged in a national strategic conversation about the structure of agricultural advocacy in Australia overall.8 This included calls to further consolidate the relationship between farmers as individuals, commodity councils and national representative structures. The argument underpinning this proposal was that, while individual organisations may be effective, the somewhat ad hoc development of the representative system undermined efficiency and effectiveness (Bettles 2014). This is a broader political project, which would involve a significant reduction in organisational overlap but also the resolution of explicit and underlying tensions between competing organisations and views about agricultural policy.9 Thus the scale of this proposed change cannot be underestimated.
Specific attempts have been made to develop formal structures to address cross-sector animal protection activism. Many of these have not been successful, or have not been sustained. For example, the NFF established the short-lived Livestock Industry Group in 1983 to provide a determinant, holistic, cross-sector working group on animal welfare activism (Graham 1983). At the state and commodity council level, the value of a co-ordinating role for animal protection issues is recognised by smaller AIOs. Peak organisations can be referred issues that cross either jurisdictional or sectoral boundaries. In this view, issues can be identified locally, then ‘filtered up’ to peak structures (interview: CEO, Queensland Farmers’ Federation, 16 April 2013). This can only occur, however, where industry segments maintain a strategic and longer-term ‘horizon view of things’ (interview: general manager [policy], NFF, 14 November 2014).
This has not always occurred. Even when issues have been identified well in advance, some commodity councils are loath to intrude on others’ remit. This can be to their own detriment. In the 2011 management of live exports, excessive deference to other commodity councils’ sphere of control led the Cattle Council of Australia (CCA) to:
deal with that in a reactive way, unfortunately, and make such a mess with things we’d really have to get boots and all involved very quickly . . . Now, the live exporters have their own big council, Australian Live Export Council. And in a normal set of circumstances you left them to drive those sorts of issue. It’s their bailiwick. That’s where we’ve got these nice little boxes – but this really genuinely is a crossover issue, [it] crosses over to the producers and the live exporters. So, through [peak red-meat commodity council] the Red Meat Advisory Council, a lot of debate [went] on, and it seemed that the Cattle Council’s constituents’ interest [was] to get this sorted because it affects our members that rely on live-export trade for income. Some areas, there’s no other choice. (Interview: J. Toohey, 4 July 2014)
Thus, effective co-ordination of animal welfare and protection policy appears to have eluded the sector. The NFF in 2013 admitted to failing in its attempts to address animal protection issues in a unified way, conceding ‘a history of sectoral response to animal welfare issues’ (Sefton & Associates 2013, 43).
In addition to structural siloisation, a number of factors contribute to this lack of co-ordination between industry actors.
The first barrier to effective collaboration is the disparate state of environmental awareness amongst the public, especially regarding animal protection issues. Commodity councils from the chicken and pork sectors, for example, report occasional use of systematic surveying (interview: a representative of the chicken industry, 31 January 2014) and focus groups (interview: A. Spencer, 23 June 2014) on this topic.10 Others have less structured environmental scanning practices (interview: E. Forbes, 9 April 2014). This may be problematic, as public opinion can be fast-moving. But it also stems from the difficulty of establishing a truly informative set of measures in an area where industry considers public opinion to be unstructured and volatile (interview: J. Toohey, 4 July 2014; E. Forbes, 9 April 2014). Where high-welfare products exist, retailers (interview: a representative of the retail industry, 22 April 2014) and highly integrated industries (particularly eggs) are best placed to measure the conversion rate of concern into high-welfare product options, but the movement of this type of information across the sector can be limited by the desire of retailers to ensure they have better intelligence than their suppliers.
Second, relationships can be very pragmatic and groups may not support related enterprises where both welfare standards and the economic value of the practice are low. A good example of this is jumps (hurdle and steeple) racing in South Australia. With low levels of participation (O’Sullivan 2015a) and a comparatively high injury rate to horses (Ruse et al. 2015),11 the South Australian Jockey Club has pushed for the sport to be wound up by the state government (ABC News 2015). While this may be thought to reflect the susceptibility of marginal enterprises with ‘poor’ welfare records to legislative bans, this is not strictly the case.12 In this example the opportunity cost of using racing facilities for jumps compares unfavourably to thoroughbred racing, making this a pragmatic decision by the jockey club to push out the last of the jumps competitors (in comparison, a temporary suspension in Victoria in 2010 was lifted by Racing Victoria; McManus et al. 2012). This argument about industry size and susceptibility to regulation is born out in a counter example: the comparative unwillingness of political elites to entertain blanket prohibitions on exotic circuses (Browne 2012). In the latter case, neither opportunity cost nor direct competition with zoos exists.
Third, breakages between different economic sectors produce barriers to industrial collaboration. Some of these are simply related to the social and/or other distance between industries that might otherwise have strong grounds for collaboration. Wool producers and laboratory researchers, for example, face similar campaigns (international secondary boycotts), by similar APOs (PETA [USA]), over similar issues (inherent practices in their use of animals). Other breakages are related to conflicting stakeholder interests. This can produce conflict between industrial actors over what appear to be symbolic slights but are in fact more significant in nature.
An example of this is the 2013 Coles–Animals Australia ‘Make it possible’ campaign. In this in-store promotion, Coles sold Animals Australia–branded shopping bags, in line with the positioning of Coles as a supplier of certified high-welfare products (free-range, RSPCA-approved and grass-fed). The promotion, similar in structure to the retailer’s cross-promotion with Landcare Australia, was not received well by the agricultural sector. Farmers threatened to boycott Coles and its parent company, and to refuse to supply them. In this case Coles significantly misjudged the sensitivity of farming communities towards Animals Australia (Clark 2013), and the role of downstream industries in pushing for increased animal welfare standards that primary producers see as antithetical to their profitability. But this shows how these two groups have very different sets of stakeholder relationships that drive their commercial concerns. Importantly, while the NFF was successful in getting Coles to withdraw from the promotion,13 the channelling of displeasure through the federation (FarmOnline 2013) illustrates the weakness of suppliers relative to retailers. Using their representative body to engage with Coles presented fewer long-term risks in confronting one of the two major grocery retailers in Australia, one with massive market power over individual suppliers.
Finally, as this demonstrates, mediating structures or organisations are rarely able to broker agreements between APOs and AIOs. The ongoing dominance of issue management by individual commodity councils means that organisations with a history of dealing with cross-cutting and social issues are not seen as natural solutions to welfare issues. This has been observed nationally, but also among SFOs:
I think that’s one of the challenges for the policy environment, and my observation of industry bodies and how they’ll react to it, is there isn’t any real proactive discussion going on with . . . those people who believe that animal welfare standards are too low . . . [The policy domain] still has very strong camps and polarised debates . . . and therefore that’s a very difficult environment for someone like our organisation to sort of try and put our hand up and say, ‘We’d like to broker a better relationship here,’ as we would do in environmental issues. (Interview: CEO, QFF, 16 April 2013)
Here the disconnect between APOs and the environmental movement is significant: the integration of environmental pressure groups into negotiated processes in other areas of policy-making has not been mirrored in the animal domain.
The comparatively scattered response to animal welfare and protection policy reflects a comparatively low salience of the issue to AIOs in Australia over many years. This, however, has been changing. Respondents report that the importance of these issues for AIOs has been increasing steadily in recent years, across a range of organisations (interview: general manager [policy], NFF, 14 November 2014). For the dairy industry, animal welfare has become a far more salient issue in the last decade and is now a ‘top five’ issue (interview: W. Judd, 19 April 2013), up from a mid-level issue just five years ago (Queensland Dairyfarmers’ Organisation 2009). This shift has coincided with Voiceless focusing on dairy welfare as a neglected ecological niche among APOs. Similar, if less dramatic, changes in significance were reported by the other commodity councils and industry organisations interviewed for this volume.
Responses to this shift have also included the institutionalisation of new structures designed specifically to embed welfare policy development in organisational activity. Racing includes regular board items on welfare (interview: E. Forbes, 9 April 2014). The Cattle Council of Australia, in establishing a subcommittee system in recent years, formed an Animal Health subcommittee with explicit remit to work on animal protection issues. The NFF has set up a taskforce to consider welfare issues.14 In 2010 the Australian Professional Rodeo Association appointed an animal welfare representative to drive policy development and training. For many respondents, this reflected a desire to become ‘proactive’ on the issue:
My attitude has always been that . . . if we see our own issues in association or as a federation, we need to be addressing them. Because we say, ‘We love the animals, and we look after animals’, if there’s anything that we see because we’re the experts, we should be addressing it ourselves and not waiting for someone else to address it for us. It must be proactive and primarily for the benefit of the animals. (Interview: S. Bradshaw, 5 May 2014)
Proactivity here includes an acceptance that APOs have been driving welfare debates during the last decade.
Thus, we need to ask the question: if AIOs see animal welfare as increasingly important – internally and externally – how do they perceive the issue? That is, following on from our discussion of what cruelty means for the Australian public in Chapter 3, what does welfare mean for those involved in animal industry?
The first meaning was introduced in our previous consideration of ‘husbandry’ and animal-rearing. When interviewed, many industry representatives suggested that there is a direct relationship between effective industry practice and good welfare. Whether it involves primary production or entertainment, this argument can be summarised as: it is in our industrial or commercial interest to maintain the highest standards, because otherwise productivity (however it is measured) will decline. This notion that ‘good husbandry equals good welfare’ allows their industrial or commercial productivity to act as a measure of good animal protection practices.
As we will see below, in this model the ideal level of welfare is reached just before the point at which productivity begins to decline. In this formulation, animal welfare depends on an economic trade-off between competing interests and their ‘utility’. These interests include:
This view of welfare considers it as a series of economic trade-offs.
McInerney (2004) argues that, contrary to the ‘good husbandry’ argument, welfare improvement in commercial settings is non-linear. As we can see in Figure 7.1, human intervention produces a more positive relationship than that which animals might experience ‘in the wild’ (point A, at which there is no human intervention in the animal’s health), rising to a point of maximal welfare (B, at which there is a positive intervention). However, for further productivity to be gained from animals beyond this point, society must accept declining levels of animal welfare (negative utility for the animal, with the possibility of negative externality to society if they ‘care’). In extremis, productivity can reach a point of negative value (point E), where both productivity and welfare rapidly decline (for example, working an animal past exhaustion; this point is indicated in the figure by the dotted arrow). In this type of economic analysis, welfare debates exist in the shaded area of zone C, where productivity and welfare are economic trade-offs necessitating a political rather than technical debate. The debate is political in nature because it is about the authoritative allocation of utility to different groups due to the increased costs of production.
Figure 7.1. McInerney’s ‘conflicts between animal welfare and productivity’ model (adapted). (A) ‘natural’ welfare/non-intervention, (B) ‘maximal welfare’, (C) ‘desired/appropriate’ welfare range, (D) ‘minimal welfare’ and (E) system collapse. Simplified and annotated from McInerney (2004, 18).
As an abstraction this model overplays similarities between sectors. There is no simple ‘unit of welfare’ comparable to monetary costs and profits, and so welfare is measured in different ways for different types of animals and in different contexts. The value of this model lies in its demonstration of two factors. First, and most simply, the model shows how economic value is privileged in the shaping of welfare policies. Thus, in a discussion of hot-iron cattle branding – an activity largely abandoned in most of Australia because it can be replaced with other, less painful stock management and identification systems – the welfare calculus follows this exact formulation:
You go to any property, particularly the big ones up north where they’ve got hundreds of thousands head of cattle – whatever we bring in, they need to maintain viability . . . They have welfare in mind . . . it’s in their interest to look after the welfare of the animals or else they’ll not make as much money as they would otherwise. But at the moment, particularly with the drought and bits and pieces, they are really doing it tough and so it’s a balancing act for them. (Interview: J. Toohey, 4 July 2014)
Second, it shows that signals about value can be complex. Wells et al. (2010; 2011) researched wool producers’ decisions about abandoning mulesing following the PETA (USA) campaign, during the period in which the industry had committed to phase out the practice by 2010. In their research, they found that decision-making included:
In addition, Wells et al. identify that interaction with farmers who had already voluntarily phased out mulesing was significant in shaping the decisions of others to adopt above-minima welfare practices. The willingness of some producers to abandon the practice voluntarily demonstrates that decision-making using strict cost–benefit analysis is moderated by a range of factors associated with local norms and expectations, as well as the practical capacity for improved welfare.16 Additionally, the value of this model becomes less informative as we move away from strictly economically rational sectors.17
Overall, animal welfare policy and protection campaigns have become significant for industry, but are largely only seen through an economic lens. In addition, while producers in theory might be expected to have no preference about where they sit on the animal welfare curve provided any lost productivity can be recouped from their buyers, this does not appear to be the case. AIO constituents do not perceive a willingness by the public to accept higher retail costs in exchange for welfare gains. The NFF has reported that many primary producers see animal protection primarily as a threat to their major concern: profitability. Where activist campaigns move other AIOs to adopt standards that are enforced upstream, their limited market power relative to retailers does not always provide producers the opportunity to add value (Sefton & Associates 2013, 53).18 Utility, in this model, can be generated at a different point of the value chain, with cost being shifted to producers.
For some, activist campaigns represent more than simply a risk of increased production costs. These organisations are cognisant of the risk of reaching a ‘tipping point’. While the general community may have little interest in animal welfare, this lack of interest is sustained by a general sense of trust in industry. As the CEO of Australian Pork Limited observed, his consumers would switch from pork to another meat should they lose confidence in the industry’s ability to provide appropriate welfare:
They are not fickle about that switch, but they are definite about it . . . if they see a systemic problem with our industry, over time they will make that shift . . . They don’t change their mind quickly. But if they get piece[s] of evidence one after the other, they will make the shift. (Interview: A. Spencer, 23 June 2014)
This points to an additional concern in some sectors: that their members are not as motivated about animal protection – as a risk – as are sector leaders, making mobilisation and response less effective.
The Victorian Farmers’ Federation, for example, lists animal welfare as a primary threat to farming in its promotional materials (Victorian Farmers’ Federation 2014), and SFOs have referred to the need to counter activist campaigns when raising funds for industry advocacy. However, in 2014, the agricultural sector overall saw more basic economic issues as far more important than activist campaigns (see Table 7.1), although industries more recently targeted by activist campaigns reported higher levels of concern. This has implications for attempts to mobilise these constituents against activists, and reveals a perceived disconnect between profits (A), supply-chain power (B), and activist campaigns (C).
Issue | Percentage |
---|---|
Profitability (A) | 45 |
Costs / supermarket duopoly (B) | 33 |
Production costs | 29 |
Regulation | 22 |
Drought | 11 |
Minority groups and activities (C) | 10 |
Labour shortages | 9 |
Table 7.1. Primary issues affecting farmers (respondents could select more than one); n = 1,002; annotated. Guthrie and Akindoyeni (2014).
Having a largely passive membership on these issues, AIOs have been forced to pursue insider strategies to negotiate and manage policies involving the treatment of animals. Thus all major, and most minor, AIOs retain regular and enduring relationships with policy-makers and regulators, such as key public servants, enforcement personnel, and (depending on the stature of the industry) politicians. These relationships are exchange-based: industry organisations tend to offer information and program implementation capacity (they are large ‘delivery agencies’ of industry programs, directly or through their service organisations), in exchange for favoured access to key decision-makers. They may not always achieve their policy objectives, but AIOs always anticipate getting a ‘hearing’. As discussed above, these interactions are partitioned into various industry-segment silos, with these silos commonly reproduced in each jurisdiction where the industry has a significant basis of operations. Where policy is pushed up to the national level, SFOs, the NFF, and only the largest commodity councils tend to have enduring and regularised relationships with policy-makers.
To some extent this suits a close, closed policy-making style that tends to keep policy development out of the public eye, and, as Halpin (2005b, 145) has observed, often out of the gaze of parliaments, by keeping policy in the administrative space where possible. This is the source of a common belief that AIOs have ‘captured’ the public sector.
A popular explanation by many APOs for the perceived gap between public expectations about animal production in industrial contexts (Chapter 3) and industrial or regulatory practice is regulatory capture. Regulatory capture is one of a range of principal–agent problems in democratic practice where the complexity of the state, and the disproportionate power of some interests (commonly economic), subvert regulation, either to negate its effect (by declawing the regulator) or to provide advantages (for instance, by preventing market entry with high regulatory barriers in order to create a mono- or oligopoly; Croley 2008). This view is promoted by animal protectionists, as well as by scholars (Goodfellow 2012). A number of hypotheses are promoted:
The latter is at the heart of calls for independent animal-welfare regulatory offices (see Chapter 8).
The question of capture is a complex one. Agricultural interests, in particular, have a strong historical and structural position relative to their state interlocutors for a variety of reasons. These include history and path dependency. The significance of the agricultural sector to the Australian economy previously provided the sector with direct political influence through rural constituencies. This was entrenched in a series of closed policy networks – ‘iron triangles’ – focused on specific production segments in the form of the various marketing bodies that focused on ensuring minimum prices for commodities before the 1970s. While the relative significance of agriculture to the overall economy declined after the Second World War, the sector’s interface with government – through state and Commonwealth agriculture departments – provides the sector with an enduring key ministry with whom it is engaged. Second, while rural population decline and urbanisation have increased the overall number of non-rural seats in parliament, rural seats have a tendency towards smaller population sizes. This leads rural interests to have higher numbers of MPs than a strict one-vote-one-value model would produce (Robinson 2003). Third, the sector has developed stable and enduring peak political structures, providing greater capacity for relationship building and maintenance with bureaucrats and political elites.
On the other hand, the past 50 years have seen the dramatic dismantling of the type of policy networks that were the most prone to capture: the marketing boards. What remains is a closeness between peak bodies and agricultural policy-makers, but not the interleaved relationships that once existed in each commodity area. This residual closeness can be mistaken for capture (Botterill 2005). In considering relationships with agricultural policy-makers, Marsh and Pannell (2000) identify how the adoption of neo-liberal economic policy has shifted the role of government agencies from service provision to client-driven approaches that are based on stricter cost-recovery models. Greater accounting for the bottom line requires a willingness of producer groups to pay for government services, and for state service providers to pay greater attention to the public interest in co-investment in services.
Further, the micro-economic reform agenda since the 1980s forces policy-makers to consider interests from across the economy. This gives the representatives of other economic interests, such as importers, wholesalers and retailers, a metaphorical ‘seat at the table’. Policy-makers may need to consider the wider implications of any support for industry through the lens of public interests and public goods, and/or to consider free-trade arguments. This is one reason why governments have yet to substantially respond to producers’ concerns about concentration at the retail end.
The wider implication is that agricultural interests have, through the disciplining effect of free markets and neo-liberalism, a significantly smaller array of policy options to draw upon, while at the same time having their policy representations channelled towards agriculture departments and rural political representatives. This is evidence of a declining structural power-base in policy networks, if not at the level of regularised interactions with bureaucrats. These enduring relationships are strongest at the state and territory level, where regionalised programs and activities are commonly generated and co-managed, but their influence has declined over the last decade. The non-prioritisation of ‘producers’ (including primary industries and manufacturing) in post-Keynesian economic thought has given transporters, wholesalers and retailers greater influence, particularly when it comes to competition policy at the national level. Overall, argue Cockfield and Botterill (2013), the policy-making process relevant to rural and regional industry tends to be one of long periods of incrementalism based on an overarching policy model (first protectionism, then adjustment, now global free markets). Within this framework, agricultural interests have a favoured seat at the policy-making table, but only to the extent to which this input fits into the dominant policy model of the day.
The implication for policy-making around animal welfare and protection issues is clear. The bias towards incrementalism is a strong one and provides stability for producers in dealing with regulatory change. Agricultural interests will retain a strong capacity to influence the design and implementation of regulation given their close relationships with policy-makers in this area. However, this tight control is limited to a very focused subset of the policy-making landscape, and is subject to external shocks. As Cockfield and Botterill (2013) argue, this incrementalism has been subject to considerable and radical punctuations to which the whole of Australian agriculture has tended to eventually succumb, albeit with a willingness by the state to help with adjustment to the new state of affairs. We have seen this model in the ACT, where cage-free production was not simply regulated out of existence; instead, the territory government paid adjustment payments to producers. The industry did not ‘win’ this conflict, but its losses were moderated and paid out.
Halpin’s observation that the policy role played by AIOs is often sub-parliamentary may reflect a waning capacity or desire to win ‘big fights’ in the public arena. As Ian Randles observed:
We’re prisoners here of our own rhetoric, in some respects. We often say, ‘This is an industry that Australia can’t do without. This is an industry that the whole pastoral economy revolves around. The Kimberley will fall over for instance, or northern Queensland, if we don’t have this industry.’ Maybe it will, maybe it won’t. I don’t know. Once you start that, then you’re suggesting you’ve got more capacity than you really have. (Interview: 30 September 2013)
By ‘digging in’ to retain relevance and influence, in Halpin’s words, and by their reluctance to fight policy debates in public, AIOs have lost much of their political legitimacy and thereby their political capacity. This is reflected in the suspicion evident in some APO criticisms of industry – insider politics can be seen as illegitimate because it is shielded from popular participation (Tham 2010, 251).
This has led a variety of organisations to experiment with the formation of new types of relationship to address the issue of legitimacy and the allegations of capture. The most tentative has been at the level of ad hoc meetings between key AIOs and APOs. In some cases, this produces positive interactions that are marked by genuine information exchange (interview: R. Cox, 2 October 2013); in others, outcomes are less positive. The latter often results from the proximity of interactions to activist campaigns; meetings that take place during or close to the start of a campaign provide little perceived value to AIOs (interview: A. Spencer, 23 June 2014). One industry representative described hosting a visit with an APO that produced few enduring results and little trust, ‘just so they can say they’ve been on a chicken farm’ (interview: a representative of the chicken industry, 31 January 2014).
Better initial meetings may lead to enduring and regular if unstructured interactions between organisations (interview: W. Judd, 19 April 2013). These may produce useful levels of trust that result in information exchange and the resolution of concerns in informal ways that, in more hostile contexts, might ‘blow up’ (interview: CEO, QFF, 16 April 2013). For some organisations, this may lead to ‘backchannels’ of communication that reduce conflict, or are necessary where organisational stakeholders would be intolerant of meetings with ‘enemy’ organisations (some AIOs will not meet with organisations they perceive as an existential threat, but some will). Trust between organisations of this type, however, takes time to build, and negative interactions may limit potential relationships for long periods of time (interview: an animal welfare advocate, 5 September 2014). In some cases, this allows AIOs to ‘shop’ for preferred APOs with whom to form partnerships, demonstrating the value of mutual exchange in cross-validating organisational legitimacy.
Some of these exchanges are formalised. The most significant and amenable APOs willing to do this are the RSPCAs. The RSPCAs’ relationships with industry are complex, and include purely informal information exchange, representation in organisational policy-making, shared committee memberships, and formal commercial or cost-recovery relationships. Of the latter, RSPCA-branded standards processes have been discussed in detail, but the society’s formal relationships with AIOs also include programs like the PIAA’s ‘Dogs Lifetime Guarantee Policy on Traceability and Rehoming’. This program sees dogs purchased from PIAA members provided a guarantee of rehoming should they become abandoned or unwanted at any time. This is an interesting program because – on paper – it extends a lifelong duty of care over companion animals by the industry body. More significantly, it does not really seem necessary: PIAA members sell around 65,000 dogs a year nationally. Given the number of rehomed dogs to date remains small, the organisation’s membership would appear to have ample capacity to place these animals themselves. But the PIAA has utilised the agreement with the RSPCA for other internal and external reasons. Internally, the decision to outsource re-homing reflects an unwillingness by industry members to accept the cost and responsibility of the program (what if an animal cannot be homed?). Thus the industry body has socialised the cost of the program across its members.19 Externally, the program gives the comparatively unknown industry association stronger legitimacy through association with the strong welfare brand. This was on display in 2015, when the organisation used the program in making a case to retain industrial-scale pet breeding and retail sales in NSW, even in the face of opposition to these practices from the RSPCA itself (Joint Select Committee on Companion Animal Breeding Practices in NSW 2015).
Within AIOs, a special category of industrial workers exists: veterinarians (and their associated support staff) and laboratory animal officers. Both are professional groups of workers, in that they have a duty to their clients, the wider public, and their profession. This category of animal workers has ethical codes of conduct regulated by legislation, organisational governance systems and convention. Strong adherence to these codes is necessary to protect the welfare of the animals with whom they work, but these workers are usually employed or paid by animal owners (although some are employed by APOs or by the state). Unlike many other professional groups (Cribb and Gewirtz 2015), veterinarians and animal-welfare officers have two clients, whose interests may not coincide – or, from a strong rights or abolitionist perspective, may be fundamentally at odds. This tension is recognised within the professions.
As Williams, observes, this often leads to veterinarians playing a mediating role between the interests of animal owners and wider community standards in the course of their working day:
We live in countries with agriculturally based economies, where human use of animals is accepted by the majority of the population – including, quite obviously, the veterinary profession. So, in accepting such use, and given the competitive and global nature of the agricultural business of today, it’s inevitable that farmers’ aims are constantly to improve efficiency of production so as to be able to keep costs as low as possible. However, the line between increasing productivity and animal welfare cost is a fine one. A combination of a greater understanding of the effects of stress on animals as well as increasing scrutiny from society in general means that there is a continuing shift – that may be incremental but is also persistent – as to where that line is drawn. (2002, 2)
The formal policy of the Australian Veterinary Association (AVA) is to encourage its members to get involved with local animal welfare societies (Australian Veterinary Association 1997).
Some have suggested that negotiating this conflict places considerable moral stress on people in these professions. Fawcett (2013, 213–4) has argued that the considerably higher than average rate of suicide among vets results from pressures associated with their unavoidable involvement in activities that disproportionately prioritise non-animal interests. She cites the example of the practice of euthanasing animals purely for reasons of convenience (such as when the owners of a pet move house). This may be the case, and certainly it appears that proximity to regular euthanasia lowers inhibitions around suicide. However, in a recent analysis of data from 2002–2012 in Australia, Milner et al. (2015) argue that a variety of factors are at play in the profession’s suicide rates, including moral stress unique to the profession, but also issues that affect other professionals (such as high self-expectations and workload) and other rural workers (isolation), and having access to an easy means of death.20
Depression and burnout appear to be spread across the spectrum of veterinary practice, although small-animal practice (i.e. those treating companion animals) seems to involve additional stress. As Hatch et al. (2011, 465) argue, this is likely caused by the higher intensity of relationships between clients and their animals in non-industrial settings, combined with unrealistic expectations of veterinary intervention, but it may also be associated with the fact that individuals from rural backgrounds are more likely to work in large-animal practice (such as industrial veterinarians). As we saw in Chapter 3, those with rural backgrounds score lower on the Animal Attitude Scale, and so may suffer reduced moral stress.
Certainly tensions are evident between the reasons why people enter the profession and the practical realities of their work. In a survey of university veterinary students in Queensland, Verrinder and Phillips (2014) identified the motivations of young people coming into the profession. In their analysis, students are primarily and overwhelmingly motivated by care for animals over an interest in animal industry or personal rewards (Table 7.2). Over time, a clearer understanding of the realities of the profession are associated with stress and some disenchantment, which, as noted, is more common among those without prior exposure to animal industry (Heath 2002).
Reason for studying veterinary science | Primary motivator |
In the top three |
---|---|---|
Enjoyment in working with animals | 57 | 117 |
Helping sick and injured animals | 50 | 101 |
Improving how animals are treated | 10 | 55 |
Interest in science | 7 | 49 |
Using practical, hands-on skills | 5 | 48 |
Becoming part of a valued profession | 3 | 21 |
Wanting a physical, outdoor job | 3 | 18 |
Farming background | 2 | 9 |
Developing a profitable animal industry | 2 | 3 |
Good job security | 2 | 5 |
One of the hardest programs to get into | 1 | 4 |
Other | 2 | 7 |
Family or friends work with animals | 0 | 5 |
Financially rewarding job | 0 | 3 |
Table 7.2: Primary reason for studying veterinary science (n = 144). Verrinder and Phillips (2014).
But this ethical tension is also important in shifting the internal regulatory norms of professional organisations like the AVA. The significant role played by students in highlighting ethical challenges to the status quo is seen in their advocacy for enhanced welfare standards on campuses across Australia (O’Sullivan 2015a). As Verrinder and Phillips (2014) have found:
The majority of students were concerned about animal ethics issues and had experienced moral distress in relation to the treatment of animals. Most believed that veterinarians should address the wider social issues of animal protection and that veterinary medicine should require a commitment to animals’ interests over owners’/caregivers’ interests.
Key figures in the animal welfare movement such as Dr Andrew Knight, for example, emerged from this very type of ethical conflict in the teaching of veterinary practices, and the issues that motivated his move from practice to advocacy still exist in veterinary teaching institutions.
These issues include the refusal of some universities to provide a mechanism for conscientious objection to performing some types of medical practices on live animals, the use of ‘waste’ animals from racing (both live and dead) (O’Brien 2014), the use and handling of animals in education (interview: E. Hill, 20 August 2013) and the under-performance of universities in adopting the ‘three Rs’ of animal use in teaching and research (interview: S. Watson, 25 June 2014):
Some trends run against the overarching assumption that this type of regulatory environment will reduce animal use. The development of genetically modified animals (a form of refinement and replacement) that provide better ‘models’ for particularly human diseases, for example, is one area where increased sophistication will increase the quantum of animals used in research. Similarly, there are concerns that structural issues that drive unnecessary use (such as funding cultures that privilege programs with animal models over non-animal methodologies; H. Marston, 23 September 2013) are actively ignored by university management because animal facilities provide higher research-funding yields.
This type of institutional gap is demonstrated in survey data from animal-welfare officers (AWOs) at Australian universities. In Table 7.3 we see that welfare personnel remain in tension with managers and those they regulate in advancing the three Rs. Thus, even in these sites of increased friction, the establishment of professional oversight of animal use has not produced a ‘regulatory revolution’ since the 1980s.
Supporting actor | Average | Median | s.d. |
---|---|---|---|
University management | 4.61 | 4.5 | 2.35 |
Researchers working with animal models | 4.5 | 5 | 2.04 |
Animal ethics committee members | 3.22 | 3 | 1.22 |
Table 7.3. Animal welfare officers in Australian universities: reported support received on a scale of 1 to 10, where 1 = extreme hostility to the role, 5 = neutral (neither support nor hostility), and 10 = maximum support for the role (n = 18).
Universities have, however, been particularly significant places for activism due to their comparatively open governance structures and the diversity of members on ethics committees. Activists have been able to see the impact of their work in changes to teaching practices, particularly around the sourcing of animals for veterinary training and the use of highly invasive and/or destructive teaching practices (interview: M. France, 19 May 2014). Because of the presence of scientists, veterinarians, welfare organisations and laypersons on these committees, they also serve as a communicative bridge between different ethical and technical perspectives (Scott and Carter 1996), within a framework that still privileges human interests. More recently there has been a move towards the institutionalisation of interest groups pushing for changes in veterinary standards based on arguments about enhanced welfare more familiar to mainstream APOs than to industry. Sentient, aka the Veterinary Institute for Animal Ethics, emerged from this type of campus activism in the mid-2000s as an interest group within veterinary medicine. This group forms another bridge between APOs and the animal-using industry, thanks to the presence of veterinary professionals working both for animal welfare organisations and in animal industry.
Both veterinarians and animal-welfare research staff have interactions with a wider set of stakeholders through various formal structures intended to ensure professional ethical integrity and calibration to social norms. The formalisation of these relationships, however, is variable. As the largest recognised professional group in animal welfare, veterinarians – both individually and through the AVA – have an automatic place in consultative and decision-making structures of government pertaining to animal welfare, as well as in other institutions and as a direct member of many AIOs (for example, the NFF and the Australian Companion Animal Council), while laboratory and teaching animal professionals have both institutionally based (the Australian and New Zealand Council for the Care of Animals in Research and Teaching, or ANZCCART, and individually based (the Australian and New Zealand Laboratory Animal Association, or ANZLAA) organisations that provide a locus for the consideration of animal welfare practices in lab and teaching contexts. These organisations have reacted, in different ways, to challenges from activists (ANZCCART through organisational inclusion, ANZLAA via dialogue).
While much of this exists in the insider world of local policy and administration, the nexus between science and public visibility is significant in considering the treatment of animals in public laboratories, as well as in zoos and circuses. We can consider these three animal-use industries on a continuum from ‘pure’21 science (public labs), to a mixture of education and entertainment (zoos), to pure entertainment (circuses). Significantly in these three settings, concerns about animal welfare have focused disproportionately on particular classes of animals, predominantly companion-animal species (particularly in veterinary education), primates (in labs and zoos), and exotic animals (zoos and circuses).
Circuses have been subject to considerable pressure to abandon the use of animals as entertainers, but the most effective campaigns have centred on their use of particular exotic animals, as opposed to animal use in general (Tait and Farrell 2010). Public laboratories have seen a decrease in activism around their use of animals in general, and an increase in campaigns targeting primates in particular. This has followed the introduction of improved welfare standards. Zoos, on the other hand, are subject both to the norms of ‘welfare-focused conservationism’ (Kazarov 2008) and to an intense public gaze. It is clearly easier to justify the use of animals for science and education than it is for entertainment. Nevertheless Australian zoos have had to invest significantly in the creation of high-welfare environments and treatment programs for a range of animals (particularly apes and elephants) to ensure that keeping these animals in captivity remains socially acceptable (Tribe 2009).
AIOs are increasingly proactive in addressing the increased interest in welfare among consumers and the wider public, as well as some of the campaigns of APOs that aggressively target industry practice. On one level this is reflected in the quantity of policy development in animal welfare undertaken in the closed and private policy world of the inside track, where multiple stakeholders are engaged in negotiating acceptable practices incrementally. This can often take the appearance of ‘running dead’ on an issue: resisting change or making minimal adjustments based on a view that external pressure is inconstant and may abate. Often, this is a very effective strategy, as seen in the case of mulesing, where the cost of changes to welfare standards was spread out over a longer timeframe than activists demanded, with individual organisations leading change based on their own sense of the market.
This, however, provides an overly saccharine view of adjustment that misremembers the sense of ‘ambush’ experienced by industry actors, and underplays the frustration felt by more established APOs when their long-running campaigns and warnings were not heeded. The ongoing salience gap between individual industry actors and their more attentive representative AIOs raises a question: can industry effectively and proactively manage animal protection advocacy in the long term? While some issues remain largely consistent over time, in that APOs have maintained a core set of concerns over a long period, some industry actors are concerned that other industry members can be obtuse in recognising repeated warnings about welfare issues that present a significant risk (interview: I. Randles, 30 September 2013). Following the 2003 controversy over live-export deaths at sea, the chief executive of the peak live-export organisation compared the incident to an aircraft crash for the airline industry (AAP 2004): that is, an unfortunate but predictable event that necessitated a review of procedures, would have a negative effect on popular opinion, but would soon pass out of the public’s memory. Such complacency significantly contributed to the conditions that led to crisis in 2011.
In addition, the ‘hit and run’ nature of some recent campaigns (Bang 2004), as well as switching activist tactics, present challenges for industries that have adopted a static position on welfare issues. Some AIOs describe a ‘grassfire’ of activism: constantly burning but springing up in new locations unpredictably (interview: CEO, QFF, 16 April 2013). Owing in part to this, the response to external pressure often swings between adoption of new welfare paradigms and active resistance to change. These types of responses tend to occur in the more public political space, either because they happen in the context of well-publicised campaigns, or because the decision to change requires political legitimacy that can only be won in the public domain. In the following final section I will examine the range of responses to external pressures, from collaboration to conflict.
Major retailers are sensitive to consumer mobilisation by advocacy organisations. Data about spikes in customer inquiries filters up from individual stores to head offices (J. Healing, Coles, in Clark 2013). This has led to the adoption of third-party standards or to retailers developing their own standards where none exist, or where they prefer (usually for cost reasons) to devise their own. However, the connection between consumer advocacy and changes in the supply chain is neither linear nor straightforward. A number of factors are at play.
The first is that consumer mobilisation has the capacity to signal initial shifts in consumer sentiment (by early adopters) in advance of more wide-spread changes. Active monitoring of these by retailers can be a first step towards adapting supply chains to provide higher-welfare products. This can be a medium-term process, where welfare concerns require considerable investment in new plants and equipment. On the other hand, if consumer mobilisation produces only quick ‘spikes’ that subside once APO public campaigns end, they may reinforce retailers’ belief that consumer commitment levels are weak and unlikely to translate into a long-term willingness to pay higher prices. Further, where demand cannot be met easily and quickly, retailers and producers may adopt changes that have more to do with branding than with any significant modification of their systems and infrastructure. If this effectively allays consumer concerns, the welfare shift may be largely symbolic, although retailers are aware that this can run the risk of being seen as ‘welfare-washing’, which can itself prompt activist mobilisation and affect the retailer’s brand.
A second factor is that consumer mobilisation is strongly moderated by analysis from retailers’ own information-management systems. While APOs that mobilise consumer activism online are able to determine the success of their campaigns more actively than ever (for example, by using online petitioning systems or analysing data from their own websites), retailers employ aggregated sales data. An APO, therefore, may see a campaign as successful if it results in a high level of mobilisation (interview: L. White, 24 September 2014), whereas retailers are looking at changes in sales volume and conversion rates on a more granular level (A. Dubs, Australian Chicken Meat Federation, in Clark 2013). The exception to this, of course, is the RSPCA, which captures sales data through its RSPCA-approved product system.
Finally, behaviour can be a prisoner of expectation. Major Australian retailers are international in their orientation, following global trends closely through their environmental scanning processes, employing transnational advertising and marketing firms (which both generate new ideas and resell them into different markets), and with an international movement of management personnel. Thus one interesting explanation for the responsiveness of major Australian retailers to consumer mobilisation is that they were forewarned by the experiences of retailers overseas. Australian welfare standards, and retailers’ capitalisation of welfare to promote brand loyalty and product differentiation (particularly in the face of new, low-cost international providers such as the German retailer Aldi), has been identified as lagging behind comparative markets overseas (interview: a representative of the retail industry, 22 April 2014). Thus when Australian APOs became more active in consumer mobilisation, major retailers recognised that this was in line with the experience of their international peers, and had already prepared responses.
Overall, the ability and willingness of retailers and producers to adopt higher welfare standards depends on a number of factors:
Based on this we can compare retail – the most frequent adopter of third-party standards – with other segments of the animal industry to explain the level of pressure to respond, and the capacity and likelihood of industry to do so (Table 7.4).
Industry | Consumer demand for voluntary standards | Future demand | Do voluntary standards add value? |
Can the industry coerce or control actors further up the supply chain? |
Is there a voluntary standard available? |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Grocery retail |
Medium | Increasing | Yes (brand equivalence or competition) | Yes | Yes |
Companion animals | High | Static | Yes (trust) | No | Potentially |
Dog racing | Low | Uncertain | Uncertain | Yes | Potentially |
Horse racing |
Medium | Increasing | Risk of death of some ‘stars’ | Yes | Potentially |
Research animals, pest species | Low | Low | Uncertain, risk* | Yes | Yes |
Research animals, privileged species | Medium | Static | |||
Display animals, general |
Low | Static | Uncertain, risk if negative event | No | Potentially |
Display animals, privileged species |
Medium | Static | Yes (animal ‘stars’ can be marketed) | No | Potentially |
Table 7.4. Animal-using industries’ relationship with voluntary standards. *The majority of Australian welfare officers (66 percent) do not think implementation of the three Rs leads to improved research outcomes (using publishing as the ‘standard’ measure of research value presently dominating university performance metrics), while some perceive it as a risk because of the higher costs it would entail.
This emphasis on community perception, trust and branding highlights another key area of AIOs’ response to welfare issues and protectionism campaigns: strategic communication. In this area the media landscape has significantly changed over the last two decades. As we have seen in Chapter 4, in recent years APOs have been able to achieve increasingly regular ‘breakthrough’ campaigns with high levels of media attention. These have tended to shift media coverage of animal protection issues away from police procedurals involving offences against companion animals towards greater reporting of systematic issues about animals in production systems. This follows a deliberate strategy of lobbying with a view to changing popular opinion about the significance of animals, their treatment, and the responsibility of producers and retailers for improving welfare standards.
This success may seem surprising given the seemingly natural advantages of industry when it comes to media access and agenda setting. Industry has vastly greater financial resources for promotion. Less obviously but importantly, key animal-using industries also enjoy significant cultural privilege. As we saw in Chapter 4, these two elements – cash and culture – are connected. As Botterill (2006) argues, Australian agriculture has benefited from a deep fondness for rural life and rural people in the Australia psyche: farming is a noble profession, farmers are practical and straightforward people, rural life is healthy and wholesome, and rural communities are strong and resilient. These ideas are reproduced in the marketing language of producers and retailers. This demonstrates how farming, wrapped up as it is in history, nationalism, mythology and a politics of nostalgia, has not fully negotiated the transformation, begun in the 1970s, from privileged sector to a business just like any other.
Botterill observes that rural communities often perceive ignorance and anti-farming bias in the dominant city-based media. She argues, however, that while the accusation of ignorance is correct, that of bias is not. Farming and farmers generally receive extremely positive coverage in the Australian media, which often reproduce a nostalgic pastoral idyll. This has provided political advantages for the sector, as well as concealing some issues from wider debate. For the rural sector, however, this reliance on a reservoir of good will is problematic, based as it is on Baudrillard’s (1994) simulacrum: a self-referential media image rather than an accurate portrayal of the world. While this has obvious advantages for farming, it also presents challenges. The distance between the real and the representational heightens the risk that if reality fails to match expectations, a cognitive shock can occur. As seen with the impact of activists’ footage, this heightens the emotional response of viewers and affects trust.
The power of this myth is clear when we consider how practices that are in effect ‘farming’ are not cognitively included in this category. The clearest example is the supply of animals for laboratories and as companion animals (so-called puppy farms). These commercial breeders do not have an established commodity council, nor the symbolic respect of being ‘real farmers’. This lack of cultural deference has made it easier for these sectors to be brought into regulatory dialogues and to be subject to state intervention. In Victoria and NSW, governments have openly entertained regulations that would scale down the size of production facilities, something that would be unthinkable in ‘real farming’.22
Attempts by farming organisations to acquaint citizens with conventional farm practices have struggled. Partially this is because the message is not controlled by farming organisations, but produced as commercial advertising by secondary processors and retailers. Advertising’s power lies in the reactivation of latent or pre-existing attitudes (Bullo 2014). Thus, while farmers may want to update how they are perceived to reflect modern agricultural realities, they are effectively counter-messaged and outspent by retailers and producers who are invested in more sentimental tropes.
In addition, reframing can be complex because animal welfare is complex. In work done for the chicken industry in 2012, market researchers found that communicating stocking densities as a ratio per square metre elicited a more favourable consumer response than per hectare (because of the smaller absolute numbers involved), but that attempting to create euphemisms for beak clipping (‘beak treatment’) only elicited negative responses from focus groups, presumably because it alerted consumers to practices they prefer not to consider (Brand Story 2012). The complexities of educating consumers are beyond the capacity of many AIOs, and some fear that engagement with the topic will raise the salience of the issue while not actually improving community knowledge.
This assumes that industry would win a pure ‘war of ideas’ if only consumers had the full picture, an assumption that is contestable. Since the 1980s, some industry groups have pushed for animal protection and welfare in closed, technical review processes as a means to combat the emergence of the second wave of protectionists. This was based on a belief that industry had the superior knowledge of animal welfare. The Livestock and Grain Producers’ Association of NSW,23 for example, published a report in 1980 calling for the formation of an inter-jurisdictional mechanism to review and resolve welfare concerns (Brown 1980). In describing the politics of animal welfare as ‘objectivity versus emotionalism’ (5, emphasis in original), the report clearly put industry in the first category, and dismissed APOs as having little more than lay expertise:
The diagnosis of animal health/welfare problems – mental or physical – by untrained or unqualified personnel is no more valid than the opinion of a person in the street on human medical issues. (23)
Industry has since invested money in third-party animal welfare research. In Queensland, for example, AgForce (as the Cattlemen’s Union) played a role in establishing a chair in animal welfare at the University of Queensland in the 1990s, from which the Centre for Animal Welfare and Ethics later emerged. This is not without problems, however, particularly where research outcomes clash with established practices. In these cases, the reliance on pure evidence-based policy-making is often moderated in such a way as to undermine the basis of industry’s claim to dominate knowledge. As a Western Australian SFO officer observed:
Typically the refrain you will hear is, ‘We want animal welfare decisions based on science, evidence-based’ (brackets: ‘but only if they suit us’) . . . A classic example is teeth grinding for sheep . . . So, what [farmers] do is grind [sheep’s] teeth so they don’t fall out so they can continue to graze properly and they have a longer productive life. However . . . they use an angle grinder. They put a gag in the sheep’s mouth. If you’ve ever seen it, it’s pretty confronting. And it’s commonly done because it’s considered to be prolonging the productive life of the animal . . . In Victoria, they did a substantial survey a number of years ago, I believe on 30,000 sheep with their control group, and there are no nutritional benefits for the sheep [in] grinding their teeth.24 So, these [results] are fact, science, evidence-based, okay? So, teeth grinding in the new standards would have been illegal. However, we still had people in WA saying, ‘I’ve got to grind those sheep’s teeth, otherwise they won’t be able to put on condition, I’ll have to send them to abattoir.’ But the science has been there for a number of years, so: what do you do there? A very difficult situation. And the way we did it was, we said, ‘Why don’t you just let us grind the teeth on the sheep we think need it – not all of them? Make it illegal on a flock basis.’ Because people used to do it on age basis, and we said, ‘Let’s not do that. Let’s satisfy these guys who still believe [it has] some practical basis.’ (Interview: I. Randles, 30 September 2013)
In some areas this has led industries to back away from supporting welfare research that may challenge current practices (interview: a former animal welfare officer, 1 August 2014).
Because of the overwhelming focus on production efficiency, much of the established research on production systems has failed to provide industry with useful data on welfare outcomes (interview: R. Cox, 2 October 2013). Thus, calls for the use of evidence-based policy can be less effective in smaller industry segments where research investment around welfare has not been a priority. Further, the connection between science and implementation can be problematic in those industries with large variations in operator size (interview: CEO, QFF, 16 April 2013). Thus we can see a difference between, for example, cattle on the one hand, and chicken production on the other, and connect the latter’s tighter industry integration and generally higher scale of operations to the greater capacity to develop an evidence base from that industry.
While many APOs may have been largely or completely dominated by laypeople in the 1980s, their capacity has changed considerably. The RSPCAs have always taken pride in advocating for evidence-based policy (interview: M. Mercurio, 4 June 2013). But this varies across species, locations and contexts. To some extent this is consciously managed by the RSPCAs’ willingness to engage in some issues more deeply than others. As their national CEO observed:
So, companion animals get obviously much more expertise in state and territory societies than there is on some of the nuances of farm animals or transport or wild animals. It’s not always the case but . . . [most societies] feel very confident talking about companion animals. (Interview: 24 June 2014)
Different industry organisations have different levels of regard for APOs, but in general are more likely to challenge the capacity and accuracy of smaller and more radical organisations than the larger brands. This reflects the comparative capacity of different organisations to some degree, but also the level of public acceptance that different organisations have when they claim to speak for animals. When interviewed, some industry representatives recognised that their disagreements with APOs tended to concern ethics, worldview and the interpretation of observations about production systems, rather than facts. A representative of a chicken commodity council observed:
How can you be critical [of APOs]? You can only be critical of something that is factually incorrect. I know you may not have heard that view before, and I’m sure our [member] companies [would think] it was the most ridiculous thing they’ve ever heard coming out of my mouth, but it’s true. I mean, we did go through the process at the time, [following the release of a critical report about the industry], of saying [to our members], ‘Okay, tell us what they’ve said that’s wrong, that’s factually incorrect.’ (Interview, emphasis added: 31 January 2014)
Similarly, a state-based commodity council representative observed:
I must say the Voiceless people are pretty well across production. They do their homework. I’ve got a lot of respect for them. We agree to disagree but you can have a very pragmatic discussion with them. (Interview: R. Cox, 2 October 2013)
This inability to dominate arguments about facts has become institutionalised as APOs have increased their representation in formal policy-making contexts.
Australian agricultural producers have, however, begun to take very seriously their representation in a mediatised environment where few Australians have even passing experiences with rural production systems.25 During the past decade producers have increasingly developed communications strategies designed to enhance their image and popular standing and to increase public understanding of the lived experience of primary producers (Botterill 2006, 23). This ‘agvocacy’ movement has tended to promote rural industry and country life in general, as opposed to specific issues or sectors. To some extent this was motivated by the successful media campaigns of organisations such as PETA (USA), whose campaign around mulesing was seen as presenting farmers as ignorant, barbaric and cruel. But the need for primary producers to be proactive has been reiterated by those within the sector (interview: W. Judd, 19 April 2013; Guthrie and Akindoyeni 2014), the Farm Institute (Potard and Keogh 2014) and politicians (interview: South Australian MP, 25 September 2014).
For the NFF, this takes the form of promoting agriculture as ‘a good industry’ to work in (interview: general manager [policy], NFF, 14 November 2014), which appears to reflect a desire to address welfare alongside a number of other issues, including concerns about profitability and the perception during the 2000s that rural Australia was chronically in drought. The unwillingness to tackle welfare issues head-on makes it difficult for industry to counter messages from activists effectively, and reflects the low priority placed on this issue relative to others and a reluctance to acknowledge the impact of APO campaigns.
One area where animal-using industries have increasingly taken a more assertive approach to protection issues and APO campaigns has been in the use of social media. Industry clearly recognises that the rise in social media campaigns by animal protectionists is a significant political threat (Thorne 2012), and one where industry’s financial advantages are negated by the ability of APOs to mobilise a large catchment of supporters, as discussed in the preceding chapter.
Many in industry also see social media as better suited to emotional messages and resistant to counter-messaging, although others consider this an inherent problem when dealing with urban stakeholders. The director of the Bureau of Animal Welfare reflected on the way the realities of farming practice may be at fundamental odds with the sensibilities of Australia’s urbanised community, illustrating how codes of practice and industry ‘norms’ are alienated from public understandings and sensibilities:
If you look through the codes of practice on farms, the destruction of premature calves can be quite effective. They’ve got very soft heads – one blow with a heavy mallet would kill them – and the farmers don’t like carrying rifles around in cars, it’s dangerous . . . So, you have to have an alternative. You have to accept some things. So, that’s an example where you say, ‘Well, the outcome must be the animal is knocked unconscious and then it’s killed.’ That could be another ten blows. If that was seen on TV, the community would be in outrage. (Interview: 21 August 2013)
Structurally, the failure to mobilise a large number of farmers and associated workers via social media appears to be caused by the lack of co-ordinating structures. Guthrie and Akindoyeni’s 2014 survey of farmers found that 89 percent26 supported the creation of a ‘GetUp’-like body for the sector – that is, a virtual campaigning organisation with campaign expertise and contact lists, which could organise members into campaign activities (Vromen 2015). Based on agricultural workers’ reported willingness to engage in campaigns directly (about 56 percent of survey respondents), the sector has a pool of potential participants in such mobilisation of about 25,000 people (not to mention a catchment of pro-farming supporters in the wider community).
This remains a possibility. To date, most pro-agriculture campaigns remain localised or associated with commodity councils, and tend to be in response to particular events. From the content analysis of media reporting introduced in Chapter 4, organised media coverage of welfare issues and protection campaigns is driven by crises, not proactive messaging, and between different organisations there is competition for ownership of issues rather than a clear delineation of responsibility. Some proactive campaigns also run counter to the wider desire to change the public image of farm workers as old-fashioned yeomen. For example, dairy farmers have been featured in advertising designed to highlight the ‘family’ nature of their industry as a direct counter to the notion of ‘factory farming’. Farmers are portrayed as ‘good people’ unfairly targeted by activists (A. Spencer in Clark 2013).
More recently, AIOs have sought to co-opt activists’ messages in the way that activists co-opted welfare expertise. This may involve emphasising the care and attention paid to animals by industrial workers and farming families, depicting them as caring and responsible ‘custodians’ of the animals and of the land. Recent supermarket pricing wars between the two major suppliers have focused on a small range of products (including milk and bread). In focusing on the lowest price, these campaigns have tended towards presenting the products as genericised, rather than following product differentiation strategies commonly associated with revitalising ‘commodity’ products. In response, dairy wholesaler and collectives advertising campaigns have begun to focus on producers rather than on attributes of the product itself (MacDonald 2012). Other messaging more assertively addresses activists’ claim to moral superiority. Following the 2015 Melbourne Cup, the industry website racingbase.com responded to anti-racing activism with messaging that highlighted the way industry members are themselves ‘for the animals’:
You know who really care? You know who is really hurting when these animals are injured? The ones that spend up to 16 hours a day by their side. That rise at 3am six days a week to help feed, groom and nurture these beautiful animals. The ones who have dedicated their lives to horse racing. They are the ones who are truly hurt when a tragedy happens on a racetrack. They also understand how much these animals love racing. They understand that accidents happen . . .27
Other counter-messaging aims to presenting activist organisations as elitist groups reflecting a narrow middle-class sensibility. Speaking for the Live Exporter’s Council in 2010, Alison Penfold said of APOs: ‘I think they like to see a world where everybody goes to farmers’ markets and takes their wicker baskets and shops in that form’ (in Clark 2013). Overall, this demonstrates the complexity of industry getting ‘on the front foot’ on welfare issues and industry characterisations in the wider community. The need for a coherent messaging strategy appears to be emerging in response to wider trends and a recognition of the impact of a mediatised society on generating unexpected risks. To date, however, reactivity and a failure of co-ordination have led to the continued propagation of overly sentimental views of agricultural production and, in response to crisis events, aggressive push-back.
One approach to managing negative publicity has been to limit the effectiveness of open rescue and other APO strategies by starving them of content. Some parts of the sector have actively lobbied for this approach, and their efforts paid off in August 2015 when the NSW state government introduced the Biosecurity Act 2015. Biosecurity is broadly defined as the ‘the protection of the economy, environment and public health from negative impacts associated with pests, diseases and weeds’ (NSW Department of Primary Industries 2008). In creating a general biosecurity obligation for all people in NSW, the 2015 Act requires that:
Any person who deals with biosecurity matter or a carrier [of biosecurity matter] and who knows, or ought reasonably to know, the biosecurity risk posed or likely to be posed by the biosecurity matter, carrier or dealing has a biosecurity duty to ensure that, so far as is reasonably practicable, the biosecurity risk is prevented, eliminated or minimised. (s. 22)
The 2015 Act also requires that any breach of this obligation must be reported (s. 38), and introduces new powers for the inspection and prosecution of such breaches (part 8). Maximum penalties under the act are $1,100,000 and/or imprisonment for three years.
While similar legislation was introduced in 2014 in Queensland,28 for animal activists the NSW legislation represented the first successful introduction of what they call ‘ag-gag’ laws. Previously seen in the United States, such legislation is designed to limit the effectiveness of animal activism through a combination of:
The characterisation of the 2015 Act as ag-gag is based on its broad reach, which criminalises not only activities that directly affect plant or animal health, but also those that may have negative economic impacts (which is precisely what some activist campaigns aim to achieve) (s. 13). The act aims to capture incitement, reduce the effectiveness of covert investigations, and prohibit support and conspiracy (and so may criminalise APO campaigns) (s. 307).
While neither the minister for agriculture nor his predecessor (who originated the bill prior to the 2015 NSW state election) stated that the legislation was aimed at animal activists in their second reading speeches (a significant reference point for future juridical interpretation), elements of the 2015 Act clearly respond to long-standing AIO concerns about the impact of covert filming, both on their industries and on individual workers (Gotsis and Roth 2015). In a speech to farmers, the minister with initial responsibility for the legislation stated in 2013:
It seems every week now . . . you’ve got animal activists breaking into intensive farms. In one of the cases a number of piglets died through the disturbance. We simply have to win. I’ve spoken very strongly to other government ministers in relation to this and the NSW government is now looking at what we can do in this space as well. We have to keep putting it up to city people that don’t, may not necessarily understand our farming practices and how important they are, that they cannot support these groups such as Animals Australia and cannot support what they’re doing. These people are vandals. These people are akin to terrorists. (ABC 2013a)
In preparation for the release of the new bill, the minister highlighted the importance of the legislation as a corrective to the limits of trespassing laws in preventing activists from accessing farms (Hodgkinson 2014). Previously, such trespass could incur a penalty of $550 (Inclosed Lands Protection Act 1901).
Significantly, the minister’s press release included a statement of support from the RSPCA NSW,30 putting this organisation at odds with the national body’s stated position on this type of law. To some extent this reflects a tension between some state societies and activists. In jurisdictions where the RSPCA has enforcement responsibilities, criticism of the existing monitoring of welfare standards can be seen as a de facto criticism of the performance of the society.
The timing of the NSW legislation was significant. It followed closely on the highly successful promotion of open rescue by Animal Liberation NSW in 2013, overlapped with the Four Corners special on live baiting in greyhound training, and was introduced at a time when the federal government was actively pushing a wide range of legislation focused on terrorism and terror-related offences.
The former minister for agriculture’s comparison of animal activists with terrorists reflects three important cultural and political factors. First, it expressed frustrations over the intrusion of animal protectionists into the agricultural policy domain, a space traditionally seen as an ‘iron triangle’ of industry, rural politicians and agricultural public servants (this is explored further in Chapter 8). Representatives of the pork industry, which has increasingly been subject to direct action by activists, talk about the sense of ‘violation’ felt by farmers upon discovering unauthorised entry (interview: A. Spencer, 23 June 2014). Second, it represented a response by rural-based politicians and their parties to an issue over which they risked losing support to minor parties (interview: R. Brown MLC, Shooters and Fishers Party, 18 March 2014). Third, it took place within a general climate of security fears, which have been used to justify a wide range of legislative changes (Gleeson 2014, 89). As Gleeson observes, security discourse and legislation31 often take place in the context of a real or perceived existential conflict. Thus, those AIOs most supportive of such regulations tend to be those that see activists as an essential threat to their existence.
New trespass restrictions are not the only legal challenge activists face. The Coalition Against Duck Shooting is subject to specific restrictions on rescue activities under legislation that limits non-shooters’ access to proscribed areas at particular times under the Wildlife (Game) Regulations 2012 (Victoria). Supported by both the Coalition and Labor parties, the regulations were ostensibly introduced to prevent the accidental shooting of protesters (as occurred in 2011), but have the effect of proscribing rescue actions. As with the NSW biosecurity laws, protesters have not seen this as a significant barrier so much as an opportunity to re-frame their struggle; they are no longer merely battling a dwindling number of hunters, but are now engaged in a David and Goliath struggle against the state. As one activist explained:
Three years of court cases. It wore the government out before it wore us out. And they realised that, even [though] two rescuers have received $10,000 in fines and costs, they’re back on the wetland a month later. It hasn’t stopped us. They suddenly realised that going to court was a long-running issue and rescuers were still [coming] back, and that’s been going on for years . . . Different governments as they come in have to learn that lesson. But I think it has helped us because it’s given us new angles to run on, new media angles. (Interview: L. Levy, 30 August 2013)
Others have been willing to engage in illegal actions due to a belief that they are unlikely to be significantly punished (Mark 2001). Activists have shown a willingness over several decades to accept prosecution, and media organisations have often been willing to broadcast material collected illegally.32 At times, this has led to legal victories using public-interest justifications of trespass (for example, in a trespass case involving Parkwood eggs in 1997). This is a problem for industry, particularly when activists are not prohibited from using the ‘proceeds’ (usually video footage) of their crimes (interview: R. Cox, 2 October 2013).
In South Australia, attempts to prohibit the use of covert surveillance devices have been made twice in the last decade (2012 and 2014).33 This legislation would have criminalised the publication of material gathered covertly without court approval (which would only be granted if it was deemed in the public interest). The legislation is interesting in that its potential effect on APOs was only identified after it was developed and it is doubtful that industry expressed an interest in such legislation before it was underway (interview: T. Franks MLC, 26 September 2014). The bill was opposed by a variety of social interests, including the Law Society of South Australia (White 2013), activist organisations and, most significantly, media organisations and journalists (Dobbie 2015).
The mobilisation of media organisations in opposition to this legislation was not only fatal to its passage, but also served to undermine key justifications for the bills. Feeling the legislation would impinge on the work of journalists, media organisations pushed back strongly against the new laws. In doing so, they made the same criticisms of such legislation commonly made by activists: the laws would restrain free speech, increase costs associated with litigation, and encourage the abuse of court processes. Journalists have been drawn into legal disputes between agricultural interests and activists on a number of occasions in Australia. When this happens, the involvement of the media often strengthens the public-interest defence of invasive activism. This was the case with Australian Broadcasting Corporation v Lenah Game Meats (2001), in which a Tasmanian-based producer of possum meat had obtained an injunction against the ABC broadcasting footage obtained by Animal Liberation members. In this case, the injunction was overturned on public-interest grounds (Little 2014, 260–1). The media’s involvement or endorsement can create a ‘halo effect’ for activists, whose work becomes associated with investigative journalism. In July 2014, an episode of Today Tonight Adelaide (Channel 7) featured footage of animal mistreatment obtained by activists, interposed with hidden-camera footage filmed by the program’s own crew. Investigations into animal mistreatment – ‘defenceless animals at the mercy of factory farms and puppy breeders’, in the words of the voiceover (Archer 2014) – was afforded moral equivalency with the human victims usually featured on the program. The activists did not appear in the show, but the reporter adopted their argot. In some cases, media organisations have even ‘commissioned’ footage from activists, thereby blurring the boundaries between activists and journalists and increasing the scepticism agricultural producers feel about parts of the media.
Thus, while some AIOs see the explicit or implicit use of anti-activist laws as a useful tool against activist campaigns, the evidence to date tends to demonstrate that in adopting this strategy, the industry risks being seen to be associated with heavy-handed or repressive laws. During the debate about new legislative measures, Voiceless brought out a prominent American critic of ‘ag-gag’ to attack the intent and legitimacy of new laws, while reiterating the idea that industry must have ‘something to hide’ (O’Sullivan 2015d).
APOs, meanwhile, have pre-emptively adjusted their messaging strategies in anticipation of the new laws. Activists engaged in live rescue have been photographed and filmed wearing protective attire, highlighting their adherence to biological security measures (Sacre 2013). However, this seems to be more of a publicity tactic than a consistently adopted change in practice,34 and the effectiveness of such footage as a legal defence remains uncertain.35 Strategic lawsuits against public participation (or SLAPPs) are comparatively rare in Australia, and are sometimes the result of poor legal forethought by activists (interview: a lawyer involved in animal law, 13 May 2014).
The Abbott Coalition government’s decision to de-fund the national Australian Animal Welfare Strategy and abolish its advisory committee, which included both industry and APO representatives and technical experts (discussed further in Chapter 8), could be interpreted as a sign of sympathy with industry groups who have proposed more aggressive measures to limit the capacity of APOs. However, suggestions from industry that the Commonwealth investigate and remove the charity status of Animals Australia were not heeded (Bettles 2013),36 and the federal government has not formally supported overtly ag-gag national legislation (the Criminal Code Amendment [Animal Protection] Bill 2015 was introduced as a private member’s bill by a Liberal senator from Western Australia).37
Thus, AIOs have won, on a very uneven basis, some legal tools with which to confront the APOs’ strategic challenge. To some extent, this mirrors the similar successes of farming organisations in the 1970s and 1980s in expanding exemptions from potential cruelty prosecutions by changing legislation to provide blanket exemptions for accepted and normal farming practice (that is, exemptions for the status quo). These exemptions prevented aggressive calls for the use of state power against primary producers, a significant legislative win against a new set of challenging organisations with a very marginal political status.38 Forty years later the legislative victories against APOs are far more modest. The likelihood of a significant impact on invasive trespass and filming is, however, limited, although the high penalties theoretically possible under the 2015 Act may have a strong deterrent effect on activists in NSW. Overall, however, the industry’s lobbying has achieved a quasi-policy solution at best: while the laws have real potential, their effect is largely a symbolic service to a beleaguered industry’s stakeholders. APOs are likely both to challenge the constitutionality of the laws, and to carry on undeterred by existing legal sanctions. If anything, the prospect of prosecution under the new laws increases the newsworthiness of future APO actions in NSW, and provides APOs with a connection to other social movements similarly targeted by ‘anti-protesting’ provisions.
The response of animal-using industry in Australia to issues of animal welfare has shifted over the last few decades. Having long been in a privileged position as protected insiders, animal agriculture maintains an advantage relative to activists in incremental policy processes, but this advantage is not automatically shared by other animal industry groups, and has not prevented producers and retailers from voluntarily adopting higher welfare standards, putting pressure on other commercial actors. The shift towards more open public communication has been slow but noticeable, and has included co-operative, communicative and combative approaches. In the latter case, AIOs have shown that they maintain important and enduring relations with policy-making elites. We will examine the role of these elites in the next chapter.
1 Activities that have commercial elements, but are not operated strictly for profit. In the context of animal protection and welfare, these can include hobby farming and recreational activities associated with clubs, where commercial opportunities cluster around largely voluntary activities.
2 The Queensland Farmers’ Federation and Primary Producers South Australia, for example, are peak bodies of commodity councils, and therefore mirror the NFF’s membership structure.
3 As Halpin (2004) observes, the strictly voluntaristic nature of SFOs has seen their memberships declining. Levies, therefore, represent a realistic way to ensure financing for industry support without recourse to the use of general taxation (a transfer) or SFO funds (which may encourage free-riding).
4 AIO rural research and development corporations (RRDC) owned by industry include the Australian Egg Corporation Limited (enabled by the Egg Industry Service Provision Act 2002), Australian Livestock Export Corporation Limited (LiveCorp) (Australian Meat and Live-Stock Industry Act 1997), Australian Meat Processor Corporation (Australian Meat and Live-Stock Industry Act 1997), Australian Pork Limited (Pig Industry Act 2001), Australian Wool Innovation Limited (Wool Services Privatisation Act 2000), Dairy Australia Limited (Dairy Produce Act 1986), and Meat and Livestock Australia (Australian Meat and Live-Stock Industry Act 1997). The sole government-owned RRDC is the Fisheries Research and Development Corporation (Primary Industries Research and Development Act 1989).
5 Australian Pork Limited, however, combines the activities of a commodity council and a service organisation, reflecting the size of the industry.
6 A good example would be the promotion of ‘grass-fed’ meat by producers as being of better quality. The MLA is forced to avoid these issues, as it services both pasture and lot feeders (interview: J. Toohey, 4 July 2014).
7 Two examples are significant. The first is the selective breeding of animals likely to produce or reproduce known genetic defects (a negative outcome for animals) in order to meet the definition of purebred. Breeding standards can be important in exacerbating these problems. The second is required physical modifications to animals. For example, some cattle-breed associations require hot-iron branding of animals, and are given exemptions from anti-cruelty legislation.
8 ‘Project Streamline and Strengthen’, following the recommendations of the Newgate Report, commissioned by the NFF.
9 Queensland, for example, has two SFOs: the Queensland Farmers’ Federation (not an NFF member) and AgForce (an NFF member) that have had mixed relationships over the last decade (conflict, co-existence, collaboration, cross-membership). AgForce represents a merger of commodity councils (cattle and cane growing).
10 The dominant market research focuses in general terms on product characteristics and demand.
11 Although in recent years Ruse has observed an improvement in the safety of jumps racing in Australia, steeple racing remains the most dangerous to horses.
12 Sponsors and third-party users of racing venues were targeted by activists opposed to jumps in South Australia, which did have an impact on the profits of venues associated with the practice (interview: T. Franks MLC, 26 September 2014).
13 Technically Animals Australia asked Coles to stop selling the bags, but this was widely interpreted as a decision by Animals Australia that allowed Coles to ‘save face’ (ABC News 2013b) while ensuring the APO maintained a positive relationship with the retailer.
14 There does not appear to be any significance in the name; ‘taskforce’ normally refers to a special organisation with a limited scope of operations and a limited timeframe (interview: general manager [policy], NFF, 14 November 2014).
15 Which, as of 2015, is mixed. Brokers report interest from European buyers and sellers in the EU market in non-mulesed wools, but limited interest in domestic Chinese production (Locke 2015). This would indicate that mixed switching in the industry, and investment in longer-term solutions (such as genetic breeding to reduce the risk of fly strike), have been effective in adjusting supply to demand.
16 Some of this clearly has an economic basis. Thus, for example, the use of electrical immobilisers in remote areas – a technique that permits surgery on large animals by forcing muscular contraction, but does not provide pain relief – is often justified with reference to a ‘lack of veterinarians’ (interview: director of a bureau of animal welfare, 21 August 2013). This lack, however, could be factored into the model as a welfare cost that would significantly change the economics of cattle production in remote areas. This shows the problem of the economic model: it trades tangibles (money) against intangibles (units of welfare, externalities) that are highly and subjectively discountable.
17 For AIOs operating on a less strictly economically rational basis, this model is moderated by a range of other drivers that relate to cultural norms and expectations about what constitutes appropriate standards of care and treatment. This can lead to what might be described in a strictly economically rational model as ‘over-investment’ in care. Such distinctions can be seen in industries where there is a mix of high-end, economically successful participants and a large number of quasi-hobby or marginal actors. A good example of this is in equestrian industries, where there is an ‘over-investment’ in animal care over strict productivity calculations (interviews: D. Dekker, 17 April 2013; E. Forbes, 9 April 2014).
18 This emphasis on the power of primary production relative to downstream actors in the supply chain has the impact of drawing international debates and issues into the domestic policy conversation. International campaigns may directly affect domestic production if transnational APOs target Australian producers. More indirectly, the use of global supplier standards by transnational corporations often embeds responses to welfare issues fought in other jurisdictions. In some cases these issues are more or less directly transferable to the Australian setting (such as chicken-density stocking levels; interview: a representative of the chicken industry, 31 January 2014). In other cases, such as moves by retailers away from feed-lot beef to ‘pasture-fed’ meat, the driving concerns are less relevant to Australia (interview: J. Toohey, 4 July 2014). In the latter case, feed-lot production is a major animal protection issue in the USA, in part due to issues of agricultural economic distortions associated with farm subsidies that do not exist in the Australian context (Marcus 2005, 188–9).
19 Which may be a problematic policy design from an animal welfare perspective. If the need to rehome animals increases due to poor retail practices (such as a failure to assess or prepare potential owners), socialising the costs of rehoming will not incentivise individual retailers to improve their sales practices.
20 The majority of cases (80 percent) in the analysis employed pentobarbitone as the method of death. This barbiturate is a sedative that is also employed as a euthanasia drug in Australian veterinary practice (Australian Research Review Panel 2014).
21 Universities and research programs are increasingly co-funded or supported by commercial interests.
22 In Victoria during the November 2014 state election campaign, when issues presented by Oscar’s Law attracted a high degree of public attention, and in NSW through the mid-2015 parliamentary inquiry process.
23 1978–1987, a rival SFO to the NSW Farmers’ Association.
24 Williams (n.d.).
25 However, the extent to which this is truly new is debateable. The Farm Writers’ Association of NSW and the Rural Press Club of Victoria, for example, were founded in the 1960s. Similar initiatives followed in South Australia and Queensland. The aim of these organisations was to promote rural and farm writing, but also to form a communicative bridge between rural and urban media organisations and professionals.
26 With 33 percent strongly supportive, 56 percent quite supportive, 3 percent opposed and 8 percent neither/don’t know (n = 1,002).
27 Extract from a longer post by racingbase.com, reportedly written by a user of the organisation’s private forums before being reposted on the public page.
28 The Biosecurity Act 2014 (Qld), commencing mid-2016. Significantly, while this act also creates a general biosecurity obligation (s. 23), if focuses on failures by individuals to undertake action to minimise known (or ought-to-be-known) biosecurity risks. For this reason, the Queensland legislation has not been as controversial as the NSW legislation. Failure to act can incur a penalty of $3,000 or three years’ imprisonment (s. 24).
29 Though, as we saw in Chapter 6, the first significant case of aggressive anti-activist litigation was the declaration of the RSPCA Victoria critic Constance May Bienvenu a vexatious litigant in an attempt to prevent her push for organisational reform.
30 The CEO is quoted as saying, ‘If people have legitimate animal welfare concerns they should contact the RSPCA NSW, NSW Police or the Animal Welfare League NSW and they will investigate them, as the independent enforcement agencies for the Prevention of Cruelty against Animals Act’.
31 This type of legal restraint on disruptive political activism is not unique to the area of animal protection activism. Under the Abbott Coalition government (2013–2015), laws were proposed to limit environmental litigation, following the success of environmental activists in delaying the development of a major mining facility in Queensland (Cox and Lee 2015). Similarly, the decade to 2015 was a high-water mark for laws from both major political parties that have restricted or criminalised political protests at the state level (in Western Australia, laws have proscribed ‘dangerous behaviour’; in Victoria, police have been given increased powers to move protesters along; Queensland has introduced temporary exclusion zones; et cetera). What these laws have in common is that they are intended to reduce the impact of political activism on major economic interests and/or provide police with elective powers in policing ‘unpopular’ and non-mainstream political protest.
32 This said, there is clearly a visibility bias in evaluating the decisions of journalists, as there is no systematic data on what proportion of illegally obtained footage is deemed not to be in the public interest and is turned down by media organisations. In this way, the conduct of journalists, acting as proxies of the public, is invisible in the legal discussion of ‘ag-gag’.
33 The Surveillance Devices Bill 2014 was defeated in the upper house by the Opposition and the South Australian Greens. The 2012 bill lapsed due to the prorogation of Parliament.
34 For example, in 2012, Animal Liberation Victoria staged a demonstration in Federation Square, Melbourne with over a hundred supporters wearing disposable clean suits (Webb 2012). In a publicised open rescue in 2015, however, activists were shown in situ wearing street clothing with latex gloves (Carney 2015).
35 As Gotsis and Roth (2015) observe of the civil trespass suit Windridge Farm Pty Ltd v Grassi (2011, 254 FLR 87), claims by the defendant that they adhered to biosecurity measures akin to those seen on Animal Liberation NSW’s 60 Minutes appearance failed to satisfy the judge, who awarded additional costs for the veterinary inspection of animals on the property.
36 This may indicate learned wariness of this aggressive tactic. During the Howard Coalition government (1996–2007) attempts were made to delist organisations that were seen as being political in nature from the register of charities; registration provides legitimacy, as well as taxation advantages, to organisations and their donors (Hamilton and Maddison 2007). These changes were subject to a successful legal challenge.
37 Senator Chris Back, previously a large-animal veterinarian.
38 However, even at this time these changes were contained within wider ‘modernisation’ of legislation, so do not represent unalloyed anti-activist measures. This is discussed in more detail in the next chapter.